Friday, April 24, 2009:
Weighting the debating of rating
By Gavin R. Putland
Rod Land, my colleague across the ditch, has drawn my attention to
a
“discussion document” distributed by the Far North
District Council (Kaikohe, NZ). The FNDC is proposing to change the
base of council rates from the Land Value (LV), which is the value of
the land or site alone, to the so-called Capital Value (CV), which is
the value of the land plus artificial improvements (including
buildings). The first page of the document stresses that
“NO decisions have yet been made” (bold type in the
original), but admits that “the council likes the look of CV
rating.”
How strongly the council prefers CV may be inferred from the tables
on pages 3 & 4, which purport to list the pros and cons of the two
systems. Notice that (a) the first table has the alleged
advantages of CV in the left column and the second has the alleged
disadvantages of LV in the right column, so that the CV proponents get
the first and last word, and (b) the points purporting to
favour CV are more numerous. Let me address problem (a) by reversing
the order of the two tables (before combining them into one). And let
me address problem (b) by adding a comment under each point
[italicized, in square brackets] explaining it further and
occasionally suggesting that it belongs somewhere else.
Land Value (LV) advantages:
|
LV disadvantages:
- LV makes little recognition of the ability to pay
[True. A family that has borrowed heavily to build a $150,000
house on a $150,000 lot has less capacity to pay than a speculator who
has bought an adjacent $150,000 vacant lot. But under LV they pay the
same rates bill. The only recognition of capacity to pay is that
richer people tend to live in more desirable suburbs, which have
higher land values but not necessarily higher building
values.]
- LV is more prone to large valuation and rates swings
[True. Because values of buildings are limited by construction
costs, fluctuations in “property” values are actually
fluctuations in land values. So if rates are levied on land values
only, they will better respond to changes in values, hence changes in
... er ... capacity to pay. So why isn't this in the
“advantages” column?]
- LV is not currently addressing rating anomalies in coastal
areas
[The supporting text implies that the “anomalies”
are the large increases in rates bills on the west coast, where land
values have risen much more than on the east coast — the
implication being that this “disadvantage” would be
alleviated if those who have missed out on increases in property
values paid a higher share of the rates!]
- LV tends to support growth pressure
[True if we define “growth pressure” as adding to
the supply of accommodation, which LV rating does not deter in any
way. But shouldn't we rather classify the demand for accommodation as
growth pressure, and the supply of accommodation as relief of the
pressure?]
- The share of rates relative to the benefits received and
services used can be disproportionate
[True if “received” and “used” are
defined narrowly enough. Land values are heavily influenced by the
availability of services on the land, but not by whether the services
are actually consumed. If that's a problem, the solution is to charge
for actual consumption of the services — not to change the
rating base to CV.]
|
Capital Value (CV) advantages:
- Most councils see CV as a fairer way to rate
[So true that when Dunedin implemented CV just over two decades
ago, the council split the General Rate into a “Separate
Rate” and “Special Rate” in order to bypass the
ratepayers' right to demand a referendum to reverse the decision. So
true that Wellington implemented CV by a process that had to be
retrospectively legalized by the Central Government. So true that the
ratepayers' right to a direct vote on the rating system was abolished
by the Labour-led Central Government in 1989, clearing the way for CV
to be imposed across the country. (See my
submission to the Royal Commission on Auckland
Governance.)]
- CV better reflects the ability to pay
[Yep. Under CV, the family that has borrowed to build a
$150,000 house on a $150,000 lot pays twice the rates of the
speculator who has bought the $150,000 vacant lot. CV reflects
ability to pay like Auckland Harbour reflects the city skyline:
upside-down!]
|
CV disadvantages:
- CV tends to be more complex and may require the greater use of
differentials
[True. The differentials might be used to offset some of the
perverse incentives that wouldn't arise under LV. Unless, of course,
the perverse incentives are the reason why CV is preferred, in which
case differentials might be used to make them
worse.]
- CV can adversely affect commercial activities
[The inclusion of “can” is a deliberate
understatement. If you tax buildings, you deter their construction
and therefore reduce the supply of commercial accommodation —
forcing up commercial rents — and reduce the supply of
residential accommodation for potential customers and employees. It's
a double whammy for business. And this is being proposed in the midst
of the worst global recession since the Great
Depression.]
|
As the “discussion document” asks, in large italic type
at the bottom of page 4,
Which would be your choice?